Afr.j. pulil. sci. (1998), Vol. 3 No. 2, 29-48 The Political Economy of Bank Failure and Supervision in the Republic of South Africa Charles C. Okeahalam* Abstract The failure of banks has financial, economic, social and political implications. Banks serve as deposit holders and financial intermediaries. As deposit holders they are the custodians of savings and via the market for capital, transfer the savings into investment or consumption. The particular role which banks play in the modern economy is significant and accordingly they are subjected to an extensive regulatory framework to ensure that they can continue to play the role for which they have been designed and to maintain confidence in the monetary and financial system. Despite these regulations (some would argue, because of these regulations) banks still become insolvent or fail to meet the conditions for maintenance or renewal of their licences. The final arbiter of this decision is usually the central bank. In the Republic of South Africa (RSA),' it has been suggested that the central bank - Reserve Bank of South Africa (RB) - has been unduly political in determining the manner in which it has applied banking regulation and conducted its role as lender of last resort. This paper contributes to this debate by discussing the manner in which the RB has performed its role and ways in which bank supervision in South Africa can be improved. Introduction The failure of banks has financial, economic and political implications. Banks are usually subjected to two types of regulation -economic and prudential. Broadly speaking the objective of economic regulation in banking is is to ensure social welfare rights. So economic regulation encourages higher competition (in commercial banks narrow spread between deposit and lending rates), less collusion and lower industry concentration. In practice, for example, economic regulation may 1027-0353 © 1998 African Association of Political Science 30 Charles C. Okeahalam entail providing legal requirements which stipulate the minimum number of full or agency bank branches which a commercial bank must operate in particular areas. Prudential regulation is concerned with ensuring that depositors' funds are protected and the financial system is not compromised. This is done primarily by ensuring that banks are adequately capitalised by an appropriate amount and risk adjusted quality of equity. The prime practical example of prudential regulation, is that in accordance with the Basle Accord which has recently been further endorsed by the 25 Core Principles for Effective Bank Supervision 1997, banks may only lend up to a multiple of 12.5 of their risk adjusted equity capital. Of late, greater emphasis has been placed on prudential regulation with some even suggesting that economic regulation is inefficient and irrelevant. In South Africa, the regulatory process is allocated to the Reserve Bank (RB) and to the Registrar of Banks (RoB). Although overall responsibility for bank supervision (economic and prudential regulation) rests with the RB, day to day operational prudential regulation is the responsibility of the RoB. The RoB therefore is responsible for the day to day monitoring of the performance of banks. The RoB can use early warning models to determine the likelihood of failure of a bank and take appropriate action to forestall it. Depositors make explicit contracts with the financial institution in which they deposit their funds and implicit contracts with the regulator, who is also seen as the lender of last resort. Prior to the change of government in 1994, this principle appeared to work well. However, since the change of government this has not been the case and it has emerged that the RB has acted haphazardly and with partiality. It has been suggested that the role of the RB owes more to politics than it does to economics. This view is further accentuated by the track record which the RB has of coming to the rescue of financial institutions for political reasons. Ihe Second section provides a brief description of the banking industry in the RSA. The Third section discusses the role of the regulator and the too- big- to-fail- E"n C ' p l e - T h e F°urth section discusses recent incidents of bank failure in the RSA. e Fifth section assesses the ways in which the RB performed its prudential regu atory role and the political economy of the decision to rescue or not to rescue Dank or financial institution. Given the inadequacy and selective political nature of bank regulation in the RSA, the Sixth section suggests ways in which the ank regulation framework might be improved. The Final section concludes. of the South African Banking Industry 1 t h I a a ^a'r'y w e " developed banking sector which uses advanced si 1 °8^a n c l management information systems. At first blush, it appears fairly - A 1 C baking sector in that it is dominated by four major "core" banks memC ated B a " k S o f S o u t n A f r i c a L i m ited (ABSA), Standard Bank Invest- *30™'0" L ' m i t e d (Stanbic), First National Bank Holdings Limited (FNB) imited (Nedcor).2 Core banks are banking institutions whose failure The Political Economy of Bank Failure and Supervision in SA 31 would create systemic instability in the domestic banking system and the national economy. Since the authorities consider the continued existence of the core banks as essential to financial and economic stability, they will do all that they can to ensure that core banks do not fail. Because of the moral hazard of espoused unconditional support for core banks, it is unlikely that the authorities would wish to be explicit or unconditional in their support. Each of these banks has extensive branch networks. There is also a number of smaller banks which operate in specific market niches. As a result of apartheid, political pressure made many foreign banks close down and withdraw their RSA operations. After the 1994 elections, a number of foreign banking firms returned and by the end of 1997 there were 59 foreign banking firms with approved local representative offices in South Africa. This is up from 40 prior to the election. In addition, by the end of 1997, seven foreign banks had established branches. So far foreign entrants have concentrated primarily on the development of corporate relationships with multinationals and domestic companies interested in foreign direct investment. Accordingly, this increase in entry into the RSA banking market has increased competition in the corporate banking and stock brokering market segments of the sector, particularly since the deregulation of the Johannesburg Stock Exchange (JSE). Margins in the RSA banking market have historically been wide in comparison with those in other banking markets.-1 By maintaining very wide net interest margins, which have been facilitated by high real interest rates, the big four and the majority of other RSA banks have historically been able to report high profitability by international standards. Indeed, the influx of foreign banks and the nonintervention of the market has led only to a marginal reduction in profits of the big four banks. Furthermore, despite the periods of economic and political instability which prevailed prior to the elections of 1994, the major South African banks developed rapidly; capitalization improved, the extent and scope of use of information technology increased, risk management techniques and banking sector skills improved also. When foreign banks divested from the RSA, a small group of industrial (and in particular insurance) firms which already played a significant role in the RSA economy bought the assets of the divesting firms. This led to high concentration, which in turn increased the concentration of retail and commercial corporate lending to a greater extent than is usual in many other countries. The upshot of this is that the larger lending exposures of the banks are a greater proportion of capital reserves. The increase in competition has not yet reversed this. However, since the elections and the formal return of the RSA into international markets, the increase in capital market and exchange rate volatility and reluctance of the RB to decrease interest rates has squeezed industry margins. Increased competition has pushed down interest margins (difference between deposit and lending rates) which are now still on a declining trend and is a principle 32 Charles C. Okeahalam Table 1: Major Share holders of the Four "Core" Banks in South Africa ABSA Stanbic Sanlam(25.1) Uberty Life (39.9) Universal (25.0)a Old Mutual (20.5) Individuals (14.9) Other Corps (13.3) OldMuluaK 10)b SB Nominees (7.6)c FNB& Associates (4. l)d Gold Fields (9.1) SB Groups PF (5.0)e TransnetPF(4.3) San lam (1.6) Mine Official PF( 1.4) Slate St Bank Trust! 1 1) Eng Ind Prov Fund(0 8) Mine Employee PF (0 7) Notes: (a) Ofwhich the major shareholders are Rembrandt Holdings, Mine Employees Pension Fund and Sage Holdings. (b) Otherwise know as South African Mutual Life. (c) Standard Bank Nominees. (d) Rand Merchant Bank Holdings. (e) Standard Bank Group Pension Fund (PF). Source: Fitch-IBCA(1997). motivation of some of the larger groups in diversifying away from traditional banking products to other areas of financial services. Increased competition has also increased the demand for qualified bankers and pushed up the costs of such skills. Apart from narrowing margins, competition has clearly exposed the cost burden of the extensive branch networks of the big four banks. Indeed, 1996 estimates indicate cost/income ratios, of the big four banks, of between 65% and M»% compared to estimates of 59-65% for most of the major banks in the countries mentioned below. The big four have instituted restructuring programmes to attempt to bring their costs down to international levels. Nedcor leads the way in this regard and analysts expectations are for a cost to income ratio of approximately If, "7 a n d F N B a n d S t a n b i c